Publications Adaptation Public finance

Anticipating the impacts of a 4°C warming: what is the cost of adaptation in France?

1 September 2024 - Climate Report - By : Vivian DEPOUES, PhD / Guillaume DOLQUES / Morgane NICOL

Assessing the economic implications of climate policies is essential for steering public action. Sig­nificant progress has been achieved in assessing the costs of mitigation, particularly with the publication in 2023 of the report on the economic implications of climate action. However, as the Cour des Comptes noted in its 2024 annual public report, numerous issues surrounding adaptation continue to emerge. Our recent work has nev­ertheless enabled us to draw five initial conclusions on the subject:

 

1 – Initial estimates but no single adaptation cost in France. We have been able to calculate some initial estimates for three major sectors: build­ings, land transport infrastructure and agricul­tural crop production. These are presented in detail in the thematic sections of this document. This patchwork of different elements, of varying degrees of maturity depending on the area of activity, allows us to see the orders of magnitude of the sums involved for all economic actors. We should not, however, be too quick to calculate a single cost for adaptation in France. Such esti­mations are difficult because they depend both on the warming level that we wish to consider (and there is much work to be done to quantify the extent of vulnerability for each warming level) and on the way in which we collectively choose to prepare (with many of these choices still to be taken, as strategic visions of adaptation are yet to be defined). For example, flood prevention measures for a road may require works totalling several million euros, whereas organizing tem­porary traffic closures during flooding episodes would mean accepting a lower level of service but would also be less expensive.

 

2 – Without a more ambitious adaptation policy, unplanned reactive measures often turn out to be the costliest for public finances, already accounting for several billion euros a year. This expenditure includes the public cost of damage, the cost of repairing essential infra­structure and the cost of subsidies to overcome crisis. While in the short term a react and repair approach may sometimes seem simpler and cheaper than one based on anticipation, it is important to bear in mind that without structural adaptation, these costs will continue to rise and will cease to be exceptional. In addition to direct costs, there are wider socio-economic conse­quences (impacts on the healthcare system, labour productivity, the efficiency of transport networks, the trade balance, etc.) which will have an impact on the whole economy and reinforce territorial and social inequalities.

 

3 – Anticipation options are well understood and could be better deployed. These include, for example, promoting adaptated construction methods and appropriate architectural choices to maximize summer thermal comfort in build­ings, even without air conditioning; reinforcing certain structures or organizing maintenance differently to improve the robustness and resil­ience of infrastructure; adjusting certain cultiva­tion practices or generalizing agroecological measures to limit the effect of climate variability on agricultural production. These options can sometimes be implemented at a limited cost – particularly by incorporating adaptation into the specifications for already planned investment. Sometimes, however, they represent additional costs, or even require the mobilization of addi­tional dedicated resources. We are just beginning to appreciate the magnitude of the costs asso­ciated with the various levers of anticipation that could be activated with varying degrees of ambi­tion. However, the costs of more transformational forms of adaptation are difficult to identify.

 

 

4 – Among the anticipation options, a number pro­duce sufficient economic co-benefits to be intrinsically profitable, but this is not the case for all. This observation calls for a debate on the internalization of climate risks in economic models and the distribution of adaptation costs. The scale of the socio-economic impacts often justifies proactive public intervention, which can take several forms: the direct payment of some adaptation costs by public budgets being only one possible option among others.

 

5 – In all cases, to ensure the best possible effi­ciency and distribution of expenditure, adap­tation must be integrated into existing planning processes. The challenge is to ensure that the right warming level, at the right time in deci­sion-making and investment cycles, is always taken into account, so that we can avoid being subjected to future climate change impacts as well as overinvesting in very costly adaptation measures that are ultimately never likely to be eco­nomically justified. This requires a sequenced implementation of adaptation that considers the lifespan of investments and the reversibility of decisions, as well as a visible and stable distribu­tion of responsibilities, to ensure that the incen­tives for taking action are clear to the various economic actors.

Anticipating the impacts of a 4°C warming: what is the cost of adaptation in France? Download
I4CE Contacts
Vivian DEPOUES, PhD
Vivian DEPOUES, PhD
Research Lead – Adaptation to climate change Email
Guillaume DOLQUES
Guillaume DOLQUES
Research Fellow – Climate Change Adaptation Email
To learn more
  • 03/21/2025 Foreword of the week
    Adaptation finance in the EU: what role for insurers and other private financial institutions?

    The President of the European Commission, Ursula von der Leyen, has committed to presenting a European Climate Adaptation Plan in 2026. The European Commission has previously emphasised public budgets as the main source of coverage for climate-related disasters. But if both the EU’s and member states’ budgets are strained by competing investment priorities and high debt levels in some cases, what are the complementary avenues for financing adaptation in the EU? How can private financial actors, such as banks, insurance companies or asset management firms, support adaptation efforts, not only to ensure resilience (i.e. recovery) from climate disasters, but also to prevent impacts before they arrive?

  • 03/20/2025
    The adaptation of real estate: what roles can the financial sector play?

    Premier état des lieux et pistes sur les banques, assureurs, gestionnaires d’actifs Un besoin de clarifier le rôle des banques, assureurs dommage et gestionnaires d’actifs dans l’adaptation de l’immobilier. Alors que les effets du changement climatique sont de plus en plus manifestes, les parties prenantes de l’immobilier doivent se préparer aux conséquences du réchauffement climatique qui pourrait atteindre, d’ici la fin du siècle en France, +4°C.

  • 03/04/2025
    The adaptation reflex in public investment in practice: Pathway for 2025 and prospects

    The 3rd French national climate change adaptation plan (PNACC3) seeks to generalize an “adaptation reflex” in all public investments and all public support for investment. Operationalizing this ambition is essential for Stop investing in infrastructure, buildings and equipment that will not be ready to cope with the consequences of climate change; Seize the best opportunities available by taking advantage of investments already planned to strengthen the level of adaptation of the French economy at lower cost. 

See all publications
Press contact Amélie FRITZ Head of Communication and press relations Email
Subscribe to our mailing list :
I register !
Subscribe to our newsletter
Once a week, receive all the information on climate economics
I register !
Fermer